Searching...
English
EnglishEnglish
EspañolSpanish
简体中文Chinese
FrançaisFrench
DeutschGerman
日本語Japanese
PortuguêsPortuguese
ItalianoItalian
한국어Korean
РусскийRussian
NederlandsDutch
العربيةArabic
PolskiPolish
हिन्दीHindi
Tiếng ViệtVietnamese
SvenskaSwedish
ΕλληνικάGreek
TürkçeTurkish
ไทยThai
ČeštinaCzech
RomânăRomanian
MagyarHungarian
УкраїнськаUkrainian
Bahasa IndonesiaIndonesian
DanskDanish
SuomiFinnish
БългарскиBulgarian
עבריתHebrew
NorskNorwegian
HrvatskiCroatian
CatalàCatalan
SlovenčinaSlovak
LietuviųLithuanian
SlovenščinaSlovenian
СрпскиSerbian
EestiEstonian
LatviešuLatvian
فارسیPersian
മലയാളംMalayalam
தமிழ்Tamil
اردوUrdu
Stone Age Economics

Stone Age Economics

by Marshall Sahlins 1974 362 pages
3.92
513 ratings
Listen
Try Full Access for 7 Days
Unlock listening & more!
Continue

Key Takeaways

1. Hunter-Gatherers: The Original Affluent Society

By the common understanding, an affluent society is one in which all the people’s material wants are easily satisfied.

Challenging assumptions. Contrary to popular belief and traditional economic theory, hunter-gatherer societies were not characterized by a desperate struggle for survival. Instead, they represent the "original affluent society," achieving material plenty not through abundant production, but by desiring little. This "Zen road to affluence" contrasts sharply with modern market economies, which, despite their wealth, institutionalize scarcity by fostering unlimited wants against limited means.

Leisure and sufficiency. Ethnographic studies of modern hunter-gatherers, such as the Bushmen and Australian Aboriginals, reveal surprisingly low work hours dedicated to food acquisition—often as little as 2 to 5 hours per day. This intermittent work pattern left ample time for leisure, rest, and social activities, contradicting the notion of incessant labor. Their diets were generally adequate, and they possessed few material goods, not out of poverty, but because mobility made possessions a burden, leading to a "lack of interest" in accumulation.

A different perspective on scarcity. The concept of scarcity is not an inherent property of resources but a relationship between means and ends. Hunter-gatherers, with their finite objectives and adequate technical means, were "comparatively free from material pressures." Their "prodigality"—consuming all available food at once—was a sign of confidence in nature's abundance, not desperation. This perspective suggests that hunger, rather than being a primitive condition, has increased with the evolution of culture and the rise of civilization.

2. The Domestic Mode of Production: Underproduction as a Cultural Choice

Production is low relative to existing possibilities.

Inherent underproduction. Primitive economies, whether agricultural or pre-agricultural, often operate below their full productive capacity. This "underproduction" is not a sign of technical incompetence but an intrinsic feature of the "domestic mode of production" (DMP), where economic life is organized primarily by household units and kinship relations. Labor power is underused, technological means are not fully engaged, and natural resources are left untapped because production is geared towards specific, limited objectives—the livelihood of the producers.

Dimensions of underuse. This underproduction manifests in several ways.

  • Resource Underuse: Swidden cultivators, for instance, often utilize only a fraction of their arable land, supporting populations significantly below the land's carrying capacity.
  • Labor Underuse: Working days are often short, work is intermittent, and certain demographic segments (e.g., young adults, men in some societies) may be largely disengaged from production.
  • Household Failure: A notable percentage of domestic groups may consistently fail to meet their own subsistence needs, yet this is tolerated by the broader social system.

An anti-surplus system. The DMP is fundamentally an "anti-surplus" system. Its primary goal is to reproduce the household's customary requirements, not to maximize output or accumulate abstract wealth. This focus on "production for use value" means that work tends to halt once immediate needs are met, leading to discontinuous and unintensive labor. The system's internal logic, as described by Chayanov's Rule, shows that labor intensity decreases as a household's relative working capacity increases, further reinforcing underproduction.

3. Social Institutions Intensify Production Beyond Domestic Needs

The total empirical process of production is organized then as a hierarchy of contradictions.

Overcoming domestic limits. The inherent underproduction and potential for household failure within the Domestic Mode of Production (DMP) pose a fundamental contradiction for society's survival. To overcome this, primitive societies enlist "superstructural" social institutions—kinship, chieftainship, and ritual—to mobilize households beyond their self-appointed subsistence goals. These institutions exert pressure, transforming the "private nuisance" of domestic underproduction into a public economy.

Measuring social influence. The impact of these social structures on household labor intensity can be quantitatively analyzed. By comparing a household's actual labor intensity against a theoretical "normal intensity" (Chayanov's Rule), one can measure the "social deviation" in production.

  • Mazulu (Tonga): Shows a slight overall underproduction, with some households working above their needs, but the "embryonic" political institutions limit the collective surplus.
  • Kapauku (New Guinea): Exhibits a much higher rate of surplus labor, driven by the "big-man" system. Big-men galvanize production for exchange and status, leading to a "fish-tail" distribution of labor intensity where ambitious individuals and their followers produce significantly more.

Political and kinship dynamics. Leaders, whether big-men or chiefs, stimulate production through various means:

  • Generosity and Debt: Leaders accumulate prestige and followers by being exceptionally generous, placing others in their debt and compelling their labor.
  • Public Enterprise: Chiefs organize collective activities (warfare, ceremonies, public works) that require surplus production.
  • Structural Integration: More centralized chiefdoms (e.g., Hawaii) can achieve greater intensification by integrating local groups into larger polities, though this can lead to over-exaction and rebellion, revealing the limits of kinship-based power.

4. The "Spirit of the Gift" is the Yield, Not a Mystical Force

What is the principle of right and interest which, in societies of primitive or archaic type, requires that the gift received must be repaid?

Reinterpreting Mauss's Hau. Marcel Mauss famously attributed the compulsion to reciprocate gifts in primitive societies to the hau, a "spirit of the thing given" that seeks to return to its origin. However, a closer reading of the Maori text, particularly the explanation by Tamati Ranapiri, suggests a different interpretation. The hau of a gift is not a mystical spirit, but rather its "yield" or "product."

The obligation to return the yield. The core principle is that any benefit or "return on" a gift, especially if the recipient has used it to advantage, ought to be passed back to the original donor. This is illustrated by a three-party transaction: A gives a gift to B, B gives it to C, and the valuable returned by C to B (the hau of A's original gift) must then be given by B to A. To keep this "yield" would be "incorrect" and could lead to misfortune.

Preventing capital accumulation. This interpretation reveals a profound economic principle: a gift should not become another's capital. The system is designed to prevent the accumulation of wealth through unearned increments derived from others' generosity. The hau of the forest is its fecundity, and the hau of a gift is its material yield; in both cases, benefits taken by man should be returned to their source to maintain its productiveness.

Exchange as social contract. Mauss's broader argument, that gift exchange substitutes for Hobbesian "Warre" by creating peace and alliance, remains powerful. The compulsion to reciprocate, whether driven by a mystical hau or a rational understanding of yield, serves to bind segmentary societies together, transforming potential conflict into social cohesion. The gift, in this sense, is a primitive form of social contract, a triumph of reason over the folly of war, enabling cooperation and cultural development.

5. Reciprocity: A Spectrum of Social Relations and Material Flows

A material transaction is usually a momentary episode in a continuous social relation.

Embeddedness of economy. In primitive societies, economic transactions are not isolated acts but are deeply embedded within ongoing social relations. The flow of goods is constrained by social etiquette and kinship, and conversely, specific transactions can initiate or reinforce particular social bonds. This contrasts with modern economies where economic relations are often detached from broader social contexts.

The continuum of reciprocity. Reciprocity is not a single, uniform type of exchange but a spectrum of forms, varying in the immediacy and equivalence of returns, and reflecting different degrees of sociability:

  • Generalized Reciprocity: Characterized by altruism, indefinite returns, and a repression of overt reckoning (e.g., food sharing among close kin, parental care). It is dominant in the most intimate social spheres.
  • Balanced Reciprocity: Involves direct, equivalent, and timely returns (e.g., gift exchange, payments, formal trade). Parties confront each other as distinct interests, and social relations often hinge on the material flow.
  • Negative Reciprocity: An attempt to gain something for nothing, often through haggling, chicanery, or theft. It is the most impersonal form, where participants are opposed interests seeking to maximize utility at the other's expense.

Kinship distance and morality. The form of reciprocity is strongly correlated with "kinship distance." Close kin engage in generalized reciprocity, while distant kin or non-kin tend towards balanced or negative reciprocity. Morality itself is often "sectoral," meaning that what is considered ethical behavior (e.g., honesty) varies depending on the social distance to the other party. This highlights how social structure dictates economic norms.

6. Kinship and Wealth Shape Exchange Dynamics

The span of social distance between those who exchange conditions the mode of exchange.

Rank and generosity. Beyond kinship distance, social rank significantly influences the form of reciprocity. Higher rank often entails obligations of generosity ("noblesse oblige"), where material advantage may even fall to the subordinate. This "generalized reciprocity" between ranks, often paternalistic in nature, serves to:

  • Legitimize Authority: Chiefs and leaders maintain their position through lavish distributions, which are conceived as reciprocal acts, even if the material flow is unbalanced.
  • Mobilize Labor: Generosity creates indebtedness and followership, enabling leaders to galvanize production beyond household needs.
  • "Starting Mechanism": For aspiring big-men, calculated generosity is a key strategy to build influence and prestige, transforming personal ambition into social power.

Wealth and sharing. Differences in wealth also compel specific forms of exchange. In communities where everyone faces periodic hardship, wealth disparities often trigger generalized reciprocity, especially for urgent goods like food.

  • Compulsory Sharing: Wealthy individuals are expected to share their abundance, often under social pressure (e.g., fear of envy, social ostracism).
  • Windfall Generosity: Large catches or unexpected abundance often lead to widespread sharing, reinforcing social bonds and demonstrating generosity.
  • Scarcity Drives Generosity: Paradoxically, it is often scarcity, not sufficiency, that makes people generous, as mutual aid ensures collective survival.

Contextual variations. The interplay of kinship, rank, and wealth creates complex exchange patterns. While generalized reciprocity tends to prevail within close-knit groups and during times of need, its extent and intensity can vary. Extreme hardship, however, can sometimes lead to a contraction of sharing, with households prioritizing their own survival, revealing the underlying fragility of social solidarity.

7. Food: A Social Barometer, Not a Commodity

Food has too much social value—ultimately because it has too much use value—to have exchange value.

Beyond mere sustenance. Food is not just a material good; it is deeply symbolic and socially charged. Its distribution serves as a delicate barometer of social relations, often employed instrumentally to initiate, sustain, or even destroy social bonds. Offering food, especially as hospitality, signifies good relations, while withholding it can signal hostility or a breakdown of social ties.

Generalized exchange for food. Common foodstuffs are more readily shared than other goods, and direct, equivalent returns for food are often considered unseemly in most social settings. This leads to:

  • Insulated Circuits: Staple foods are frequently excluded from balanced exchange or "money" circuits within the community, as demanding a return on necessities would contradict prevailing kinship relations.
  • Moral Imperative: Taboos against hunters eating their own kill or injunctions to share large game reinforce the moral value of food distribution.
  • Hospitality: Offering food to visitors, even strangers, is a common way to establish or maintain peaceful relations, often transcending typical sectoral boundaries of reciprocity.

Social value over exchange value. The principle that "food has too much social value... to have exchange value" means that its primary function is to sustain life and social cohesion, not to be a means of profit. This contrasts sharply with market economies where food is a commodity. However, this insulation is often contextual; in inter-community or inter-tribal trade, where social distance is greater, food may indeed be exchanged for other goods, as the moral constraints weaken.

8. Primitive Trade: Diplomacy and Social Tact Determine Value

The economic ratio is a diplomatic maneuver.

Beyond supply and demand. While primitive trade, even without formal markets, exhibits exchange values that respond to supply and demand, the mechanisms driving these values are fundamentally different from those in market economies. The indeterminacy of rates in internal exchanges and the absence of competitive bidding in external trade challenge orthodox economic explanations.

Social tact as a determinant. Exchange rates in primitive trade, particularly in "partnership trade" between different communities or tribes, are set by "social tact" and "diplomacy of economic good measure." This involves a conscious effort to give a generous return relative to what has been received, avoiding "unpleasantness" that could lead to conflict. This over-reciprocation serves as a peace treaty, demonstrating a willingness to live and let live in a context where force is decentralized.

Mechanisms of diplomatic exchange:

  • Over-reciprocation: The host often gives more than the initial "solicitory gift" from a visitor, creating a "margin of safety" and obligating the partner for future interactions.
  • Obligation to Receive: Partners are often compelled to accept goods they may not immediately need, reinforcing the social bond and ensuring future reciprocal obligations.
  • No Haggling: Direct bargaining is often forbidden or frowned upon, as it could introduce friction and undermine the social relationship.

Equilibrium through social means. This procedure of transitory unbalance, where partners alternately manifest generosity, implicitly establishes an equilibrium rate over time. The "generosity" principle, by considering the utility and labor of both parties, brings forces analogous to supply and demand to bear on the exchange rate, albeit through social rather than purely economic means.

9. Exchange Rates: Stable in Short-Term, Responsive in Long-Term

The rate of exchange takes on functions of a peace treaty.

Short-term stability. Despite the underlying influence of supply and demand, exchange rates in primitive trade tend to remain stable in the short term, even in the face of seasonal fluctuations or temporary imbalances. This stability is maintained by:

  • Moral Force: Customary rates carry significant moral weight, serving as standards of fair conduct and peace in potentially hostile intergroup relations.
  • Alternative Strategies: Instead of adjusting prices, traders might seek new partners or use overpayment to obligate existing partners, thus defending the established rates.
  • Social Absorption: The trade partnership itself, as a social relation, absorbs economic pressure, preventing immediate price changes.

Long-term adjustment. Over longer periods, however, exchange values do adjust to sustained changes in supply and demand, often influenced by external factors like the introduction of European goods. This adjustment is not achieved through market competition but through social processes:

  • Partnership Dissolution: Persistent imbalances can lead to the termination of old trade partnerships.
  • Negotiation of New Partnerships: New partnerships are formed, and through the "tactful maneuvers of reciprocal overpayment," new customary rates are established that better reflect the changed supply/demand conditions.
  • Network Modification: Significant shifts might even lead to geographical and ethnic reconfigurations of trade networks.

Social structure and economic flexibility. The economic flexibility of a primitive trade system is directly dependent on the social structure of its trade relations. The degree of sociability in a partnership (e.g., trade-kinship vs. trade-friendship) determines its capacity to absorb economic pressure and its responsiveness to supply/demand changes. The primitive trade partnership, in essence, functions as a social counterpart to the market's price mechanism, achieving equilibrium through social means rather than impersonal competition.

10. Primitive Economics: A Distinct Logic Beyond Market Principles

The decisive differences between formalism and substantivism, as far as their acceptance is at issue, if not so far as their truth, are ideological.

Challenging economism. The study of primitive economies reveals a distinct economic logic that fundamentally challenges the "formalist" approach of orthodox economics, which attempts to apply universal, market-centric models to all societies. This book argues for a "substantivist" perspective, viewing economy as a category of culture, intertwined with politics and religion, rather than a domain governed by universal rationality or prudence. The "naive economics" of anthropology, which often projects bourgeois assumptions onto primitive life, is critiqued as ethnocentric.

Culture as the economic framework. Unlike modern societies where "the economy" is a differentiated, self-regulating sphere, in primitive contexts, economic activity is embedded within broader cultural and social structures, particularly kinship. Production, distribution, and consumption are expressions of cultural values and social relations, not merely rational responses to scarcity. This means:

  • No Separate "Economy": Economic activity is a function of generalized social groups, not a specialized institution.
  • Production for Livelihood: Goals are qualitatively defined by a way of living, not quantitatively as abstract wealth.
  • Socially Determined Scarcity: "Population pressure" or "resource scarcity" are often structural problems relative to a society's cultural rules, not absolute technical limits.

Beyond the market. The book demonstrates that even when primitive trade exhibits characteristics seemingly aligned with market forces (like supply and demand influencing exchange rates), the underlying mechanisms are social and diplomatic, not competitive. The "economic problem" of provisioning society is solved through diverse cultural strategies, often prioritizing social cohesion and stability over material maximization. This perspective suggests that the evolution of economy has been a complex process, enriching technologically but also, at times, impoverishing socially, leading to unprecedented hunger in the modern era.

Last updated:

Want to read the full book?

Review Summary

3.92 out of 5
Average of 513 ratings from Goodreads and Amazon.

Stone Age Economics challenges conventional economic theories by examining hunter-gatherer societies. Sahlins argues these groups achieved affluence through limited needs rather than material abundance. The book explores concepts like the "domestic mode of production" and gift economies, emphasizing how economic practices were deeply rooted in social and cultural values. While some readers found the academic style challenging, many praised its paradigm-shifting ideas about primitive economies, leisure time, and the nature of wealth. The book remains influential in anthropology and economics, offering insights into alternative economic systems and critiquing modern capitalist assumptions.

Your rating:
4.5
12 ratings

About the Author

Marshall David Sahlins was a prominent American cultural anthropologist known for his groundbreaking work in Pacific ethnography and anthropological theory. As the Charles F. Grey Distinguished Service Professor Emeritus at the University of Chicago, Sahlins made significant contributions to the field, challenging conventional wisdom about economic systems and cultural evolution. His research focused on the intersection of culture, history, and economics, particularly in non-Western societies. Sahlins' influential works, including "Stone Age Economics," reshaped anthropological understanding of primitive economies and social structures. His ideas on reciprocity, cultural relativism, and the critique of Western economic models continue to influence scholars across disciplines.

Download PDF

To save this Stone Age Economics summary for later, download the free PDF. You can print it out, or read offline at your convenience.
Download PDF
File size: 0.32 MB     Pages: 19

Download EPUB

To read this Stone Age Economics summary on your e-reader device or app, download the free EPUB. The .epub digital book format is ideal for reading ebooks on phones, tablets, and e-readers.
Download EPUB
File size: 2.97 MB     Pages: 20
Listen
Now playing
Stone Age Economics
0:00
-0:00
Now playing
Stone Age Economics
0:00
-0:00
1x
Voice
Speed
Dan
Andrew
Michelle
Lauren
1.0×
+
200 words per minute
Queue
Home
Swipe
Library
Get App
Create a free account to unlock:
Recommendations: Personalized for you
Requests: Request new book summaries
Bookmarks: Save your favorite books
History: Revisit books later
Ratings: Rate books & see your ratings
200,000+ readers
Try Full Access for 7 Days
Listen, bookmark, and more
Compare Features Free Pro
📖 Read Summaries
Read unlimited summaries. Free users get 3 per month
🎧 Listen to Summaries
Listen to unlimited summaries in 40 languages
❤️ Unlimited Bookmarks
Free users are limited to 4
📜 Unlimited History
Free users are limited to 4
📥 Unlimited Downloads
Free users are limited to 1
Risk-Free Timeline
Today: Get Instant Access
Listen to full summaries of 73,530 books. That's 12,000+ hours of audio!
Day 4: Trial Reminder
We'll send you a notification that your trial is ending soon.
Day 7: Your subscription begins
You'll be charged on Aug 24,
cancel anytime before.
Consume 2.8x More Books
2.8x more books Listening Reading
Our users love us
200,000+ readers
"...I can 10x the number of books I can read..."
"...exceptionally accurate, engaging, and beautifully presented..."
"...better than any amazon review when I'm making a book-buying decision..."
Save 62%
Yearly
$119.88 $44.99/year
$3.75/mo
Monthly
$9.99/mo
Start a 7-Day Free Trial
7 days free, then $44.99/year. Cancel anytime.
Scanner
Find a barcode to scan

38% OFF
DISCOUNT FOR YOU
$79.99
$49.99/year
only $4.16 per month
Continue
2 taps to start, super easy to cancel
Settings
General
Widget
Loading...